By TINA ROSENBERG
Globalization
is a phenomenon that has remade the economy of virtually every nation, reshaped
almost every industry and touched billions of lives, often in surprising and
ambiguous ways. The stories filling the front pages in recent weeks -- about
economic crisis and contagion in
Globalization is meant to signify
integration and unity -- yet it has proved, in its way, to be no less
polarizing than the cold-war divisions it has supplanted. The lines between
globalization's supporters and its critics run not only between countries but
also through them, as people struggle to come to terms with the defining
economic force shaping the planet today. The two sides in the discussion -- a
shouting match, really -- describe what seem to be two completely different
forces. Is the globe being knit together by the Nikes and Microsofts and
Citigroups in a dynamic new system that will eventually lift the have-nots of
the world up from medieval misery? Or are ordinary people now victims of ruthless
corporate domination, as the Nikes and Microsofts and Citigroups roll over the
poor in nation after nation in search of new profits?
The debate over globalization's true
nature has divided people in third-world countries since the phenomenon arose.
It is now an issue in the
When I first set out to see for myself
whether globalization has been for better or for worse, I was perplexed, too. I
had sympathy for some of the issues raised by the protesters, especially their
outrage over sweatshops. But I have also spent many years in
The architects of globalization are right
that international economic integration is not only good for the poor; it is
essential. To embrace self-sufficiency or to deride growth, as some protesters
do, is to glamorize poverty. No nation has ever developed over the long term
without trade.
But the protesters are also right -- no
nation has ever developed over the long term under the rules being imposed
today on third-world countries by the institutions controlling globalization.
The
The World Trade Organization was designed
as a meeting place where willing nations could sit in equality and negotiate
rules of trade for their mutual advantage, in the service of sustainable
international development. Instead, it has become an unbalanced institution
largely controlled by the
The International Monetary Fund was
created to prevent future Great Depressions in part by lending countries in
recession money and pressing them to adopt expansionary policies, like deficit
spending and low interest rates, so they would continue to buy their neighbors'
products. Over time, its mission has evolved into the reverse: it has become a
long-term manager of the economies of developing countries, blindly committed to
the bitter medicine of contraction no matter what the illness. Its formation
was an acknowledgment that markets sometimes work imperfectly, but it has
become a champion of market supremacy in all situations, echoing the voice of
Wall Street and the United States Treasury Department, more interested in
getting wealthy creditors repaid than in serving the poor.
It is often said that globalization is a
force of nature, as unstoppable and difficult to contain as a storm. This is
untrue and misleading. Globalization is a powerful phenomenon -- but it is not
irreversible, and indeed the previous wave of globalization, at the turn of the
last century, was stopped dead by World War I. Today it would be more likely
for globalization to be sabotaged by its own inequities, as disillusioned
nations withdraw from a system they see as indifferent or harmful to the poor.
Globalization's supporters portray it as
the peeling away of distortions to reveal a clean and elegant system of
international commerce, the one nature intended. It is anything but. The accord
creating the W.T.O. is 22,500 pages long -- not exactly a free trade
agreement. All globalization, it seems, is local, the rules drawn up by, and
written to benefit, powerful nations and powerful interests within those
nations. Globalization has been good for the
It's not too late for globalization to
work. But the system is in need of serious reform. More equitable rules would
spread its benefits to the ordinary citizens of wealthy countries. They would
also help to preserve globalization by giving the poor of the world a stake in
the system -- and, not incidentally, improve the lives of hundreds of millions
of people. Here, then, are nine new rules for the global economy -- a
prescription to save globalization from itself.
1.
Make the State a Partner
If
there is any place in Latin America where the poor have thrived because of
globalization, it is
For the rest of Latin America, and most
of the developing world except
When I visited Eastern Europe after the
end of Communism, a time when democracy was mainly bringing poverty, I heard
over and over again that the reason for
What Pinochet did was to shut down
sectors of
Pinochet's second wave of globalization,
in the late 1980's, worked better, because the state did not stand on the side.
It regulated the changes effectively and aggressively promoted exports. But
Pinochet created a time bomb in
The conventional wisdom among economists
today is that successful globalizers must be like
And what if you don't have these things?
2.
Import Know-How Along With the Assembly Line
If
there is a showcase for globalization in Latin America, it lies on the
outskirts of
The Volkswagen factory is the biggest
single industrial plant in Mexico. Humans do work here -- 11,000 people in
assembly-line jobs, 4,000 more in the rest of the factory -- with 11,000 more
jobs in the industrial park of VW suppliers across the street making parts,
seats, dashboards and other components. Perhaps 50,000 more people work in
other companies around Mexico that supply VW. The average monthly wage in the
plant is $760, among the highest in the country's industrial sector. The
factory is the equal of any in Germany, the product of a billion-dollar
investment in 1995, when VW chose Puebla as the exclusive site for the New
Beetle.
Ahhh, globalization.
Except . . . this plant is not here
because Mexico has an open economy, but because it had a closed one.
In 1962, Mexico decreed that any automaker that wanted to sell cars here had to
produce them here. Five years later, VW opened the factory. Mexico's local
content requirement is now illegal, except for very limited exceptions, under
W.T.O. rules; in Mexico the local content requirement for automobiles is being
phased out and will disappear entirely in January 2004.
The Puebla factory, for all the jobs and
foreign exchange it brings Mexico, also refutes the argument that foreign
technology automatically rubs off on the local host. Despite 40 years here, the
auto industry has not created much local business or know-how. VW makes the
point that it buys 60 percent of its parts in Mexico, but the ''local''
suppliers are virtually all foreign-owned and import most of the materials they
use. The value Mexico adds to the Beetles it exports is mainly labor.
Technology transfer -- the transmission of know-how from foreign companies to
local ones -- is limited in part because most foreign trade today is
intracompany; Ford Hermosillo, for example, is a stamping and assembly plant
shipping exclusively to Ford plants in the United States. Trade like this is
particularly impenetrable to outsiders. ''In spite of the fact that Mexico has
been host to many car plants, we don't know how to build a car,'' says Huberto
Juarez, an economist at the Autonomous University of Puebla.
Volkswagen Mexico is the epitome of the
strategy Mexico has chosen for globalization -- assembly of imported parts. It
is a strategy that makes perfect sense given Mexico's proximity to the world's
largest market, and it has given rise to the maquila industry, which
uses Mexican labor to assemble foreign parts and then re-export the finished
products. Although the economic slowdown in the United States is hurting the
maquila industry, it still employs a million people and brings the country $10
billion a year in foreign exchange. The factories have turned Mexico into one
of the developing world's biggest exporters of medium- and high-technology
products. But the maquila sector remains an island and has failed to stimulate
Mexican industries -- one reason Mexico's globalization has brought
disappointing growth, averaging only 3 percent a year during the 1990's.
In countries as varied as South Korea,
China and Mauritius, however, assembly work has been the crucible of wider
development. Jeffrey Sachs, the development economist who now directs Columbia
University's Earth Institute, says that the maquila industry is
''magnificent.'' ''I could cite 10 success stories,'' he says, ''and every one
started with a maquila sector.'' When Korea opened its export-processing zone
in Masan in the early 1970's, local inputs were 3 percent of the export value,
according to the British development group Oxfam. Ten years later they were
almost 50 percent. General Motors took a Korean textile company called Daewoo
and helped shape it into a conglomerate making cars, electronic goods, ships
and dozens of other products. Daewoo calls itself ''a locomotive for national
economic development since its founding in 1967.'' And despite the company's
recent troubles, it's true -- because Korea made it true. G.M. did not tutor
Daewoo because it welcomed competition but because Korea demanded it. Korea
wanted to build high-tech industry, and it did so by requiring technology
transfer and by closing markets to imports.
Maquilas first appeared in Mexico in
1966. Although the country has gone from assembling clothing to assembling
high-tech goods, nearly 40 years later 97 percent of the components used in
Mexican maquilas are still imported, and the value that Mexico adds to its
exports has actually declined sharply since the mid-1970's.
Mexico has never required companies to
transfer technology to locals, and indeed, under the rules of the North
American Free Trade Agreement, it cannot. ''We should have included a technical
component in Nafta,'' says Luis de la Calle, one of the treaty's negotiators
and later Mexico's under secretary of economy for foreign trade. ''We should be
getting a significant transfer of technology from the United States, and we
didn't really try.''
Without technology transfer, maquila work
is marked for extinction. As transport costs become less important, Mexico is
increasingly competing with China and Bangladesh -- where labor goes for as
little as 9 cents an hour. This is one reason that real wages for the
lowest-paid workers in Mexico dropped by 50 percent from 1985 to 2000.
Businesses, in fact, are already leaving to go to China.
3.
Sweat the Sweatshops — But Sweat Other Problems More
When
Americans think about globalization, they often think about sweatshops -- one
aspect of globalization that ordinary people believe they can influence through
their buying choices. In many of the factories in Mexico, Central America and
Asia producing American-brand toys, clothes, sneakers and other goods,
exploitation is the norm. The young women who work in them -- almost all
sweatshop workers are young women -- endure starvation wages, forced overtime
and dangerous working conditions.
In Chile, I met a man who works at a
chicken-processing plant in a small town. The plant is owned by Chileans and
processes chicken for the domestic market and for export to Europe, Asia and
other countries in Latin America. His job is to stand in a freezing room and
crack open chickens as they come down an assembly line at the rate of 41 per
minute. When visitors arrive at the factory (the owners did not return my phone
calls requesting a visit or an interview), the workers get a respite, as the line
slows down to half-speed for show. His work uniform does not protect him from
the cold, the man said, and after a few minutes of work he loses feeling in his
hands. Some of his colleagues, he said, are no longer able to raise their arms.
If he misses a day he is docked $30. He earns less than $200 a month.
Is this man a victim of globalization?
The protesters say that he is, and at one point I would have said so, too. He
-- and all workers -- should have dignified conditions and the right to
organize. All companies should follow local labor laws, and activists should
pressure companies to pay their workers decent wages.
But today if I were to picket
globalization, I would protest other inequities. In a way, the chicken worker,
who came to the factory when driving a taxi ceased to be profitable, is a
beneficiary of globalization. So are the millions of young women who have left
rural villages to be exploited gluing tennis shoes or assembling computer
keyboards. The losers are those who get laid off when companies move to
low-wage countries, or those forced off their land when imports undercut their
crop prices, or those who can no longer afford life-saving medicine -- people
whose choices in life diminish because of global trade. Globalization
has offered this man a hellish job, but it is a choice he did not have before,
and he took it; I don't name him because he is afraid of being fired. When this
chicken company is hiring, the lines go around the block.
4.
Get Rid of the Lobbyists
The
argument that open economies help the poor rests to a large extent on the
evidence that closed economies do not. While South Korea and other East Asian
countries successfully used trade barriers to create export industries, this is
rare; most protected economies are disasters. ''The main tendency in a
sheltered market is to goof off,'' says Jagdish Bhagwati, a prominent
free-trader who is the Arthur Lehman professor of economics at Columbia
University. ''A crutch becomes a permanent crutch. Infant-industry protection
should be for infant industries.''
Anyone who has lived or traveled in the
third world can attest that while controlled economies theoretically allow
governments to help the poor, in practice it's usually a different story. In
Latin America, spending on social programs largely goes to the urban middle
class. Attention goes to people who can organize, strike, lobby and contribute
money. And in a closed economy, the ''state'' car factory is often owned by the
dictator's son and the country's forests can be chopped down by his golf
partner.
Free trade, its proponents argue, takes
these decisions away from the government and leaves them to the market, which
punishes corruption. And it's true that a system that took corruption and undue
political influence out of economic decision-making could indeed benefit the
poor. But humans have not yet invented such a system -- and if they did, it
would certainly not be the current system of globalization, which is soiled
with the footprints of special interests. In every country that negotiates at
the W.T.O. or cuts a free-trade deal, trade ministers fall under heavy pressure
from powerful business groups. Lobbyists have learned that they can often
quietly slip provisions that pay big dividends into complex trade deals. None
have been more successful at getting what they want than those from America.
The most egregious example of a
special-interest provision is the W.T.O.'s rules on intellectual property. The
ability of poor nations to make or import cheap copies of drugs still under
patent in rich countries has been a boon to world public health. But the W.T.O.
will require most of its poor members to accept patents on medicine by 2005,
with the very poorest nations following in 2016. This regime does nothing for
the poor. Medicine prices will probably double, but poor countries will never
offer enough of a market to persuade the pharmaceutical industry to invent
cures for their diseases.
The intellectual-property rules have won
worldwide notoriety for the obstacles they pose to cheap AIDS medicine. They
are also the provision of the W.T.O. that economists respect the least. They
were rammed into the W.T.O. by Washington in response to the industry groups
who control United States trade policy on the subject. ''This is not a trade issue,''
Bhagwati says. ''It's a royalty-collection issue. It's pharmaceuticals and
software throwing their weight around.'' The World Bank calculated that the
intellectual-property rules will result in a transfer of $40 billion a year
from poor countries to corporations in the developed world.
5.
No Dumping
Manuel
de Jesús Gómez is a corn farmer in the hills of Puebla State, 72 years old and
less than five feet tall. I met him in his field of six acres, where he was
trudging behind a plow pulled by a burro. He farms the same way campesinos
in these hills have been farming for thousands of years. In Puebla, and in the
poverty belt of Mexico's southern states -- Chiapas, Oaxaca, Guerrero -- corn
growers plow with animals and irrigate by praying for rain.
Before Nafta, corn covered 60 percent of
Mexico's cultivated land. This is where corn was born, and it remains a symbol
of the nation and daily bread for most Mexicans. But in the Nafta negotiations,
Mexico agreed to open itself to subsidized American corn, a policy that has
crushed small corn farmers. ''Before, we could make a living, but now sometimes
what we sell our corn for doesn't even cover our costs,'' Gómez says. With
Nafta, he suddenly had to compete with American corn -- raised with the most
modern methods, but more important, subsidized to sell overseas at 20 percent
less than the cost of production. Subsidized American corn now makes up almost
half of the world's stock, effectively setting the world price so low that
local small farmers can no longer survive. This competition helped cut the
price paid to Gómez for his corn by half.
Because of corn's importance to Mexico,
when it negotiated Nafta it was promised 15 years to gradually raise the amount
of corn that could enter the country without tariffs. But Mexico voluntarily
lifted the quotas in less than three years -- to help the chicken and pork
industry, Mexican negotiators told me unabashedly. (Eduardo Bours, a member of
the family that owns Mexico's largest chicken processor, was one of Mexico's
Nafta negotiators.) The state lost some $2 billion in tariffs it could have
charged, and farmers were instantly exposed to competition from the north.
According to ANEC, a national association of campesino cooperatives, half a
million corn farmers have left their land and moved to Mexican cities or to
America. If it were not for a weak peso, which keeps the price of imports
relatively high, far more farmers would be forced off their land.
The toll on small farmers is particularly
bitter because cheaper corn has not translated into cheaper food for Mexicans.
As part of its economic reforms, Mexico has gradually removed price controls on
tortillas and tortilla flour. Tortilla prices have nearly tripled in real terms
even as the price of corn has dropped.
Is this how it was supposed to be? I
asked Andres Rosenzweig, a longtime Mexican agriculture official who helped
negotiate the agricultural sections of Nafta. He was silent for a minute. ''The
problems of rural poverty in Mexico did not start with Nafta,'' he said. ''The
size of our farms is not viable, and they get smaller each generation because
farmers have many children, who divide the land. A family in Puebla with five
hectares could raise 10, maybe 15, tons of corn each year. That was an annual
income of 16,000 pesos,'' the equivalent of $1,600 today. ''Double it and you
still die of hunger. This has nothing to do with Nafta.
''The solution for small corn farmers,''
he went on, ''is to educate their children and find them jobs outside
agriculture. But Mexico was not growing, not generating jobs. Who's going to
employ them? Nafta.''
One prominent antiglobalization report
keeps referring to farms like Gómez's as ''small-scale, diversified,
self-reliant, community-based agriculture systems.'' You could call them that,
I guess; you could also use words like ''malnourished,'' ''undereducated'' and
''miserable'' to describe their inhabitants. Rosenzweig is right -- this is not
a life to be romanticized.
But to turn the farm families'
malnutrition into starvation makes no sense. Mexico spends foreign exchange to
buy corn. Instead, it could be spending money to bring farmers irrigation,
technical help and credit. A system in which the government purchased farmers'
corn at a guaranteed price -- done away with in states like Puebla during the
free-market reforms of the mid-1990's -- has now been replaced by direct
payments to farmers. The program is focused on the poor, but the payments are
symbolic -- $36 an acre. In addition, rural credit has disappeared, as the
government has effectively shut down the rural bank, which was badly run, and
other banks won't lend to small farmers. There is a program -- understaffed and
poorly publicized -- to help small producers, but the farmers I met didn't know
about it.
Free trade is a religion, and with religion comes hypocrisy. Rich nations press
other countries to open their agricultural markets. At the urging of the I.M.F.
and Washington, Haiti slashed its tariffs on rice in 1995. Prices paid to rice
farmers fell by 25 percent, which has devastated Haiti's rural poor. In China,
the tariff demands of W.T.O. membership will cost tens of millions of peasants
their livelihoods. But European farmers get 35 percent of their income from
government subsidies, and American farmers get 20 percent. Farm subsidies in
the United States, moreover, are a huge corporate-welfare program, with nearly
70 percent of payments going to the largest 10 percent of producers. Subsidies
also depress crop prices abroad by encouraging overproduction. The farm bill
President Bush signed in May -- with substantial Democratic support -- provides
about $57 billion in subsidies for American corn and other commodities over the
next 10 years.
Wealthy nations justify pressure on small
countries to open markets by arguing that these countries cannot grow rice and
corn efficiently -- that American crops are cheap food for the world's hungry.
But with subsidies this large, it takes chutzpah to question other nations'
efficiency. And in fact, the poor suffer when America is the supermarket to the
world, even at bargain prices. There is plenty of food in the world, and even
many countries with severe malnutrition are food exporters. The problem is that
poor people can't afford it. The poor are the small farmers. Three-quarters of
the world's poor are rural. If they are forced off their land by subsidized
grain imports, they starve.
6.
Help Countries Break the Coffee Habit
Back
in the 1950's, Latin American economists made a simple calculation. The
products their nations exported -- copper, tin, coffee, rice and other
commodities -- were buying less and less of the high-value-added goods they
wanted to import. In effect, they were getting poorer each day. Their solution
was to close their markets and develop domestic industries to produce their own
appliances and other goods for their citizens.
The strategy, which became known as
import substitution, produced high growth -- for a while. But these closed
economies ultimately proved unsustainable. Latin American governments made
their consumers buy inferior and expensive products -- remember the Brazilian
computer of the 1970's? Growth depended on heavy borrowing and high deficits.
When they could no longer roll over their debts, Latin American economies
crashed, and a decade of stagnation resulted.
At the time, the architects of import
substitution could not imagine that it was possible to export anything but
commodities. But East Asia -- as poor or poorer than Latin America in the
1960's -- showed in the 1980's and 1990's that it can be done. Unfortunately,
the rules of global trade now prohibit countries from using the strategies
successfully employed to develop export industries in East Asia.
American trade officials argue that they
are not using tariffs to block poor countries from exporting, and they are
right -- the average tariff charged by the United States is a negligible 1.7
percent, much lower than other nations. But the rules rich nations have set --
on technology transfer, local content and government aid to their infant
industries, among other things -- are destroying poor nations' abilities to
move beyond commodities. ''We are pulling up the ladder on policies the
developed countries used to become rich,'' says Lori Wallach, the director of
Public Citizen's Global Trade Watch.
The commodities that poor countries are
left to export are even more of a dead end today than in the 1950's. Because of
oversupply, prices for coffee, cocoa, rice, sugar and tin dropped by more than
60 percent between 1980 and 2000. Because of the price collapse of commodities
and sub-Saharan Africa's failure to move beyond them, the region's share of
world trade dropped by two-thirds during that time. If it had the same share of
exports today that it had at the start of the 1980's, per capita income in
sub-Saharan Africa would be almost twice as high.
7.
Let the People Go
Probably
the single most important change for the developing world would be to legalize
the export of the one thing they have in abundance -- people. Earlier waves of
globalization were kinder to the poor because not only capital, but also labor,
was free to move. Dani Rodrik, an economist at Harvard's Kennedy School of
Government and a leading academic critic of the rules of globalization, argues
for a scheme of legal short-term migration. If rich nations opened 3 percent of
their work forces to temporary migrants, who then had to return home, Rodrik
says, it would generate $200 billion annually in wages, and a lot of technology
transfer for poor countries.
8.
Free the I.M.F.
Globalization
means risk. By opening its economy, a nation makes itself vulnerable to
contagion from abroad. Countries that have liberalized their capital markets
are especially susceptible, as short-term capital that has whooshed into a country
on investor whim whooshes out just as fast when investors panic. This is how a
real-estate crisis in Thailand in 1997 touched off one of the biggest global
conflagrations since the Depression.
The desire to keep money from rushing out
inspired Chile to install speed bumps discouraging short-term capital inflows.
But Chile's policy runs counter to the standard advice of the I.M.F., which has
required many countries to open their capital markets. ''There were so many
obstacles to capital-market integration that it was hard to err on the side of
pushing countries to liberalize too much,'' says Ken Rogoff, the I.M.F.'s
director of research.
Prudent nations are wary of capital
liberalization, and rightly so. Joseph Stiglitz, the Nobel Prize-winning
economist who has become the most influential critic of globalization's rules,
writes that in December 1997, when he was chief economist at the World Bank, he
met with South Korean officials who were balking at the I.M.F.'s advice to open
their capital markets. They were scared of the hot money, but they could not
disagree with the I.M.F., lest they be seen as irresponsible. If the I.M.F.
expressed disapproval, it would drive away other donors and private investors
as well.
In the wake of the Asian collapse, Prime
Minister Mahathir Mohamad imposed capital controls in Malaysia -- to worldwide
condemnation. But his policy is now widely considered to be the reason that
Malaysia stayed stable while its neighbors did not. ''It turned out to be a
brilliant decision,'' Bhagwati says.
Post-crash, the I.M.F. prescribed its
standard advice for nations -- making loan arrangements contingent on spending
cuts, interest-rate hikes and other contractionary measures. But balancing a
budget in recession is, as Stiglitz puts it in his new book, ''Globalization
and Its Discontents,'' a recommendation last taken seriously in the days of
Herbert Hoover. The I.M.F.'s recommendations deepened the crisis and forced
governments to reduce much of the cushion that was left for the poor. Indonesia
had to cut subsidies on food. ''While the I.M.F. had provided some $23 billion
to be used to support the exchange rate and bail out creditors,'' Stiglitz
writes, ''the far, far, smaller sums required to help the poor were not
forthcoming.''
Is your international financial infrastructure breeding Bolsheviks? If it does
create a backlash, one reason is the standard Bolshevik explanation -- the
I.M.F. really is controlled by the epicenter of international capital. Formal
influence in the I.M.F. depends on a nation's financial contribution, and
America is the only country with enough shares to have a veto. It is striking
how many economists think the I.M.F. is part of the ''Wall Street-Treasury
complex,'' in the words of Bhagwati. The fund serves ''the interests of global
finance,'' Stiglitz says. It listens to the ''voice of the markets,'' says
Nancy Birdsall, president of the Center for Global Development in Washington
and a former executive vice president of the Inter-American Development Bank.
''The I.M.F. is a front for the U.S. government -- keep the masses away from
our taxpayers,'' Sachs says.
I.M.F. officials argue that their advice
is completely equitable -- they tell even wealthy countries to open their
markets and contract their economies. In fact, Stiglitz writes, the I.M.F. told
the Clinton administration to hike interest rates to lower the danger of
inflation -- at a time when inflation was the lowest it had been in decades.
But the White House fortunately had the luxury of ignoring the I.M.F.:
Washington will only have to take the organization's advice the next time it
turns to the I.M.F. for a loan. And that will be never.
9.
Let the Poor Get Rich the Way the Rich Have
The
idea that free trade maximizes benefits for all is one of the few tenets
economists agree on. But the power of the idea has led to the overly credulous
acceptance of much of what is put forward in its name. Stiglitz writes that
there is simply no support for many I.M.F. policies, and in some cases the
I.M.F. has ignored clear evidence that what it advocated was harmful. You can
always argue -- and American and I.M.F. officials do -- that countries that
follow the I.M.F.'s line but still fail to grow either didn't follow the
openness recipe precisely enough or didn't check off other items on the to-do
list, like expanding education.
Policy makers also seem to be skipping
the fine print on supposedly congenial studies. An influential recent paper by
the World Bank economists David Dollar and Aart Kraay is a case in point. It
finds a strong correlation between globalization and growth and is widely cited
to support the standard rules of openness. But in fact, on close reading, it
does not support them. Among successful ''globalizers,'' Dollar and Kraay count
countries like China, India and Malaysia, all of whom are trading and growing
but still have protected economies and could not be doing more to misbehave by
the received wisdom of globalization.
Dani Rodrik of Harvard used Dollar and
Kraay's data to look at whether the single-best measure of openness -- a
country's tariff levels -- correlates with growth. They do, he found -- but not
the way they are supposed to. High-tariff countries grew faster. Rodrik argues
that the countries in the study may have begun to trade more because they had
grown and gotten richer, not the other way around. China and India, he points
out, began trade reforms about 10 years after they began high growth.
When economists talk about many of the
policies associated with free trade today, they are talking about national
averages and ignoring questions of distribution and inequality. They are
talking about equations, not what works in messy third-world economies. What
economic model taught in school takes into account a government ministry that
stops work because it has run out of pens? The I.M.F. and the World Bank --
which recommends many of the same austerity measures as the I.M.F. and
frequently conditions its loans on I.M.F.-advocated reforms -- often tell
countries to cut subsidies, including many that do help the poor, and impose
user fees on services like water. The argument is that subsidies are an
inefficient way to help poor people -- because they help rich people too -- and
instead, countries should aid the poor directly with vouchers or social
programs. As an equation, it adds up. But in the real world, the subsidies
disappear, and the vouchers never materialize.
The I.M.F. argues that it often saves
countries from even more budget cuts. ''Countries come to us when they are in
severe distress and no one will lend to them,'' Rogoff says. ''They may even
have to run surpluses because their loans are being called in. Being in an
I.M.F. program means less austerity.'' But a third of the developing world is
under I.M.F. tutelage, some countries for decades, during which they must
remodel their economies according to the standard I.M.F. blueprint. In March
2000, a panel appointed to advise Congress on international financial
institutions, named for its head, Allan Meltzer of Carnegie Mellon University,
recommended unanimously that the I.M.F. should undertake only short-term crisis
assistance and get out of the business of long-term economic micromanagement
altogether.
The standard reforms deprive countries of
flexibility, the power to get rich the way we know can work. ''Most Latin
American countries have had deep reforms, have gone much further than India or
China and haven't gotten much return for their effort,'' Birdsall says. ''Many
of the reforms were about creating an efficient economy, but the economic
technicalities are not addressing the fundamental question of why countries are
not growing, or the constraint that all these people are being left out.
Economists are way too allergic to the wishy-washy concept of fairness.''
The protesters in the street, the Asian financial crisis, criticism from
respected economists like Stiglitz and Rodrik and those on the Meltzer
Commission and particularly the growing realization in the circles of power
that globalization is sustainable for wealthy nations only if it is acceptable
to the poor ones are all combining to change the rules -- slightly. The
debt-forgiveness initiative for the poorest nations, for all its limitations,
is one example. The Asian crisis has modified the I.M.F.'s view on capital markets,
and it is beginning to apply less pressure on countries in crisis to cut
government spending. It is also debating whether it should be encouraging
countries to adopt Chile's speed bumps. The incoming director of the W.T.O. is
from Thailand, and third-world countries are beginning to assert themselves
more and more.
But the changes do not alter the
underlying idea of globalization, that openness is the universal prescription
for all ills. ''Belt-tightening is not a development strategy,'' Sachs says. ''The
I.M.F. has no sense that its job is to help countries climb a ladder.''
Sachs says that for many developing
nations, even climbing the ladder is unrealistic. ''It can't work in an AIDS
pandemic or an endemic malaria zone. I don't have a strategy for a significant
number of countries, other than we ought to help them stay alive and control
disease and have clean water. You can't do this purely on market forces. The
prospects for the Central African Republic are not the same as for Shanghai,
and it doesn't do any good to give pep talks.''
China, Chile and other nations show that
under the right conditions, globalization can lift the poor out of misery.
Hundreds of millions of poor people will never be helped by globalization, but
hundreds of millions more could be benefiting now, if the rules had not been
rigged to help the rich and follow abstract orthodoxies. Globalization can
begin to work for the vast majority of the world's population only if it ceases
to be viewed as an end in itself, and instead is treated as a tool in service
of development: a way to provide food, health, housing and education to the
wretched of the earth.
Tina Rosenberg writes editorials for The
Times. Her last article for the magazine was about human rights in China.